Senin, 02 April 2018

Sponsored Links

Gale-Shapley Algorithm - YouTube
src: i.ytimg.com

In mathematics, economics, and computer science, the stable marriage problem (also stable matching problem or SMP) is the problem of finding a stable matching between two equally sized sets of elements given an ordering of preferences for each element. A matching is a mapping from the elements of one set to the elements of the other set. A matching is not stable if:

In other words, a matching is stable when there does not exist any match (A, B) by which both A and B would be individually better off than they are with the element to which they are currently matched.

The stable marriage problem, assuming heterosexual pairings, has been stated as follows:

Given n men and n women, where each person has ranked all members of the opposite sex in order of preference, marry the men and women together such that there are no two people of opposite sex who would both rather have each other than their current partners. When there are no such pairs of people, the set of marriages is deemed stable.

Note that the existence of two classes that need to be paired with each other (men and women in this example), distinguishes this problem from the stable roommates problem.


Video Stable marriage problem



Applications

Algorithms for finding solutions to the stable marriage problem have applications in a variety of real-world situations, perhaps the best known of these being in the assignment of graduating medical students to their first hospital appointments. In 2012, the Nobel Prize in Economics was awarded to Lloyd S. Shapley and Alvin E. Roth "for the theory of stable allocations and the practice of market design."

An important and large-scale application of stable marriage is in assigning users to servers in a large distributed Internet service. Billions of users access web pages, videos, and other services on the Internet, requiring each user to be matched to one of (potentially) hundreds of thousands of servers around the world that offer that service. A user prefers servers that are proximal enough to provide a faster response time for the requested service, resulting in a (partial) preferential ordering of the servers for each user. Each server prefers to serve users that it can with a lower cost, resulting in a (partial) preferential ordering of users for each server. Content delivery networks that distribute much of the world's content and services solve this large and complex stable marriage problem between users and servers every tens of seconds to enable billions of users to be matched up with their respective servers that can provide the requested web pages, videos, or other services.


Maps Stable marriage problem



Solution

In 1962, David Gale and Lloyd Shapley proved that, for any equal number of men and women, it is always possible to solve the SMP and make all marriages stable. They presented an algorithm to do so.

The Gale-Shapley algorithm involves a number of "rounds" (or "iterations"):

  • In the first round, first a) each unengaged man proposes to the woman he prefers most, and then b) each woman replies "maybe" to her suitor she most prefers and "no" to all other suitors. She is then provisionally "engaged" to the suitor she most prefers so far, and that suitor is likewise provisionally engaged to her.
  • In each subsequent round, first a) each unengaged man proposes to the most-preferred woman to whom he has not yet proposed (regardless of whether the woman is already engaged), and then b) each woman replies "maybe" if she is currently not engaged or if she prefers this guy over her current provisional partner (in this case, she rejects her current provisional partner who becomes unengaged). The provisional nature of engagements preserves the right of an already-engaged woman to "trade up" (and, in the process, to "jilt" her until-then partner).
  • This process is repeated until everyone is engaged.

The runtime complexity of this algorithm is O ( n 2 ) {\displaystyle O(n^{2})} where n {\displaystyle n} is number of men or women.

This algorithm guarantees that:

Everyone gets married 
At the end, there cannot be a man and a woman both unengaged, as he must have proposed to her at some point (since a man will eventually propose to everyone, if necessary) and, being proposed to, she would necessarily be engaged (to someone) thereafter.
The marriages are stable 
Let Alice and Bob both be engaged, but not to each other. Upon completion of the algorithm, it is not possible for both Alice and Bob to prefer each other over their current partners. If Bob prefers Alice to his current partner, he must have proposed to Alice before he proposed to his current partner. If Alice accepted his proposal, yet is not married to him at the end, she must have dumped him for someone she likes more, and therefore doesn't like Bob more than her current partner. If Alice rejected his proposal, she was already with someone she liked more than Bob.

Stable Marriage Problem Algorithm - Marriage Quotes Idea
src: i1.wp.com


Algorithm

  function stableMatching {      Initialize all m ? M and w ? W to free      while ? free man m who still has a woman w to propose to {         w = first woman on m's list to whom m has not yet proposed         if w is free           (m, w) become engaged         else some pair (m', w) already exists           if w prefers m to m'              m' becomes free             (m, w) become engaged            else             (m', w) remain engaged      }  }  

The Gale-Shapley Algorithm - YouTube
src: i.ytimg.com


Optimality of the solution

While the solution is stable, it is not necessarily optimal from all individuals' points of view. The traditional form of the algorithm is optimal for the initiator of the proposals and the stable, suitor-optimal solution may or may not be optimal for the reviewer of the proposals. An example is as follows:

There are three suitors (A,B,C) and three reviewers (X,Y,Z) which have preferences of:

A: YXZ   B: ZYX   C: XZY   X: BAC   Y: CBA   Z: ACB

There are 3 stable solutions to this matching arrangement:

suitors get their first choice and reviewers their third (AY, BZ, CX)
all participants get their second choice (AX, BY, CZ)
reviewers get their first choice and suitors their third (AZ, BX, CY)

All three are stable because instability requires one of the participants to be happier with an alternative match. Giving one group their first choices ensures that the matches are stable because they would be unhappy with any other proposed match. Giving everyone their second choice ensures that any other match would be disliked by one of the parties. The algorithm converges in a single round on the suitor-optimal solution because each reviewer receives exactly one proposal, and therefore selects that proposal as its best choice, ensuring that each suitor has an accepted offer, ending the match. This asymmetry of optimality is driven by the fact that the suitors have the entire set to choose from, but reviewers choose between a limited subset of the suitors at any one time.


Woman Looking Laptop Screen Words Stable Stock Illustration ...
src: image.shutterstock.com


Stable marriage with indifference

In the classical version of the problem, each person must rank the members of the opposite sex in strict order of preference. However, in a real-world setting, a person may prefer two or more persons as equally favorable partner. Such tied preference is termed as indifference. Below is such an instance where m 2 {\displaystyle m_{2}} finds tie between w 3 & w 1 {\displaystyle w_{3}\&w_{1}} and w 2 {\displaystyle w_{2}} finds tie between m 1 & m 2 {\displaystyle m_{1}\&m_{2}} .

m 1 [   w 2   w 1   w 3   ]             w 1 [   m 3   m 2   m 1   ] {\displaystyle m_{1}[\ w_{2}\ w_{1}\ w_{3}\ ]\ \ \ \ \ \ w_{1}[\ m_{3}\ m_{2}\ m_{1}\ ]}

m 2 [ ( w 3   w 1 ) w 2 ]             w 2 [ ( m 1   m 2 ) m 3 ] {\displaystyle m_{2}[\left(w_{3}\ w_{1}\right)w_{2}]\ \ \ \ \ \ w_{2}[\left(m_{1}\ m_{2}\right)m_{3}]}

m 3 [   w 1   w 2   w 3   ]             w 3 [   m 2   m 3   m 1   ] {\displaystyle m_{3}[\ w_{1}\ w_{2}\ w_{3}\ ]\ \ \ \ \ \ w_{3}[\ m_{2}\ m_{3}\ m_{1}\ ]}

If tied preference lists are allowed then the stable marriage problem will have three notions of stability which are discussed in the below sections.

A matching will be called weakly stable unless there is a couple each of whom strictly prefers the other to his/her partner in the matching. Robert W. Irving has extended Gale-Shapley algorithm as below to provide such weakly stable matching in O ( n 2 ) {\displaystyle O(n^{2})} time where n is size of stable marriage problem. Ties in men and women's preference list are broken arbitrarily. Preference lists are reduced as algorithm proceeds.

A matching is super-stable if there is no couple each of whom either strictly prefers the other to his/her partner or is indifferent between them. Robert W. Irving has modified the above algorithm to check whether such super stable matching exists and outputs matching in O ( n 2 ) {\displaystyle O(n^{2})} time if it exists. Below is the pseudo-code.

A matching is strongly stable if there is no couple x, y such that x strictly prefers y to his/her partner and y either strictly prefers x to his/her partner or is indifferent between them. Robert W. Irving has provided the algorithm which checks if such strongly stable matching exists and outputs the matching if it exists. The algorithm computes perfect matching between sets of men and women, thus finding the critical set of men who are engaged to multiple women. Since such engagements are never stable, all such pairs are deleted and the proposal sequence will be repeated again until either 1) some man's preference list becomes empty (in which case no strongly stable matching exists) or 2) strongly stable matching is obtained. Below is the pseudo-code for finding strongly stable matching. It runs in O ( n 4 ) {\displaystyle O(n^{4})} time which is explained in the Lemma 4.6 of .


The Stable Marriage Problem (2012 Nobel Prize Economics) - YouTube
src: i.ytimg.com


Similar problems

The assignment problem seeks to find a matching in a weighted bipartite graph that has maximum weight. Maximum weighted matchings do not have to be stable, but in some applications a maximum weighted matching is better than a stable one.

The stable roommates problem is similar to the stable marriage problem, but differs in that all participants belong to a single pool (instead of being divided into equal numbers of "men" and "women").

The hospitals/residents problem - also known as the college admissions problem - differs from the stable marriage problem in that a hospital can take multiple residents, or a college can take an incoming class of more than one student. Algorithms to solve the hospitals/residents problem can be hospital-oriented (as the NRMP was before 1995) or resident-oriented. This problem was solved, with an algorithm, in the same original paper by Gale and Shapley, in which the stable marriage problem was solved.

The hospitals/residents problem with couples allows the set of residents to include couples who must be assigned together, either to the same hospital or to a specific pair of hospitals chosen by the couple (e.g., a married couple want to ensure that they will stay together and not be stuck in programs that are far away from each other). The addition of couples to the hospitals/residents problem renders the problem NP-complete.

The matching with contracts problem is a generalization of matching problem, in which participants can be matched with different terms of contracts. An important special case of contracts is matching with flexible wages.


Stable Marriage Problem Algorithm - Marriage Quotes Idea
src: i1.wp.com


Implementation in software packages

  • R: The Gale-Shapley algorithm (also referred to as deferred-acceptance algorithm) for the stable marriage and the hospitals/residents problem is available as part of the matchingMarkets and matchingR packages.
  • API: The MatchingTools API provides a free application programming interface for the Gale-Shapley algorithm.
  • Python: The Gale-Shapley algorithm is included along with several others for generalized matching problems in the QuantEcon/MatchingMarkets.py package

Irving's Algorithm - The Stable Roommates Problem - YouTube
src: i.ytimg.com


See also

  • Assignment problem a similar problem where edge weights are commutative
  • Stable roommates problem a similar problem, but with one set of size n and n-1 preferences
  • Nash equilibrium
  • Hungarian algorithm an algorithm to solve weighted bipartite matching problem
  • Matching (graph theory) generalized matching problem in graphs
  • Rainbow matching for edge colored graphs

Stable Marriage Problem Algorithm - Marriage Quotes Idea
src: tse1.mm.bing.net


References

Textbooks and other important references not cited in the text


USMP Worked Example: 1.1 - YouTube
src: i.ytimg.com


External links

  • Interactive Flash Demonstration of SMP
  • https://web.archive.org/web/20080512150525/http://kuznets.fas.harvard.edu/~aroth/alroth.html#NRMP
  • http://www.dcs.gla.ac.uk/research/algorithms/stable/EGSapplet/EGS.html
  • Gale-Shapley JavaScript Demonstration
  • SMP Lecture Notes

Source of the article : Wikipedia

Comments
0 Comments